Title | : | How States Think: The Rationality of Foreign Policy |
Author | : | |
Rating | : | |
ISBN | : | 0300269307 |
ISBN-10 | : | 9780300269307 |
Language | : | English |
Format Type | : | Hardcover |
Number of Pages | : | 304 |
Publication | : | Published September 5, 2023 |
To understand world politics, you need to understand how states think. Are states rational? Much of international relations theory assumes that they are. But many scholars believe that political leaders rarely act rationally. The issue is crucial for both the study and practice of international politics, for only if states are rational can scholars and policymakers understand and predict their behavior.
John J. Mearsheimer and Sebastian Rosato argue that rational decisions in international politics rest on credible theories about how the world works and emerge from deliberative decision‑making processes. Using these criteria, they conclude that most states are rational most of the time, even if they are not always successful. Mearsheimer and Rosato make the case for their position, examining whether past and present world leaders, including George W. Bush and Vladimir Putin, have acted rationally in the context of momentous historical events, including both world wars, the Cold War, and the post–Cold War era.
By examining this fundamental concept in a novel and comprehensive manner, Mearsheimer and Rosato show how leaders think, and how to make policy for dealing with other states.
How States Think: The Rationality of Foreign Policy Reviews
-
Overall, I felt like this book was a fine introduction to several rationality theories in terms of states’ foreign policies. This, as one would expect, prompts the authors themselves to dive into highlighting the theoretical framework of their study (which was about half of the book) before demonstrating how their ideas can be used to practically determine the rationality or irrationality of one country’s actions or another’s.
Although I enjoyed the examples provided by the author, at times I felt some of their interpretations of historic events lacked sufficient evidence, and several ideas lacked rationality. Mainly, I found it hard to view historical events in a black-and-white way, such as rational or not rational, and often times thought about why they can’t be both?
Another small critique that I have is that the book focused too much on highlighting the main points of the authors’ opinions through repetition, which made it feel quite monotonous. -
Decent read, I prefer John’s articles to this. Repeats itself and is very boring in the first 100 pages. The second half makes up for it. Worth a read
-
The counter-point to Richard Ned Lebow's Cultural Theory, and ultimately just as much of a mixed bag of correct observations and mythbusting coupled with some questionable suppositions of its own.
Overall, the argument that states are more likely to behave rationally than nonrationally is correct, and the idea of comparing the greater amount of examples of this with the lesser amount of nonrational counterpoints is on point. State rationality should be taken as a default setting if no contrary information is to be found.
BUT
I am not confident that the proportion is overwhelming enough to be complacent about this. Mearsheimer's work itself serves as a counter-point when it comes to his (correct) focus on the Israel Lobby sabotaging rational behavior in Washington DC. That same elite is behind the Iraq, Libya, and Syria interventions as well, all of which strenghtened jihadist power and weakened the American position abroad.
The authors list credible vs non-credible theories early in the work and while for the most part they are correct, placing neoclassical realism in the non-credible camp showed the same strange inconsistency as exists in the prior point about the Israel lobby. It is claimed that neoclassical realism cannot uphold both state survival as the ultimate goal while also allowing for a wide chance of irrationality to take root as this creates a self-contradiction. But neoclassical realism does not contradict itself, stating in effect that boutique ideologies and irrational behavior thrive with ruling cliques for a time but eventually usually give way to survival when the chips are down. America's force posture in the Middle East may be unwise and self-destructive, but it does not threaten its own state survival. This is, perhaps, why it happens. The luxury wars of a complacent power.
This being said, the criteria for what rational vs irrational policy making in uncertain conditions is among the best and most succinct definitions I have come across in a book. -
Overall a well written book, but theoretical debate becomes heavy at times in the first half. The examples quoted are from high profile historical events involving major powers. I wonder if rationality is that much in play in decisions taken by smaller third world countries. Is absence of rational policy making a major reason behind these countries' underdevelopment and poverty?
-
“Those who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat it.”
These famous words have been reiterated so many times since George Santayana wrote them in 1905 that they have become a cliché. Mark Twain was probably more accurate when he asserted that “history doesn’t repeat itself, but it often rhymes.”
To pick up rhyming schemes, we examine history. And as we examine history, we are puzzled. Why would a nation initiate hostilities against each other fully cognizant of the repercussions? Why would a state choose certain political strategy when it is obvious that utility can’t be maximized? What ruminations went through the minds of the policy makers and rulers? Are their actions to be dismissed as mere folly, or did they stem from an, albeit elusive, valid rationale?
Do states act rationally?
It has become commonplace for American leaders to dismiss their foreign adversaries as “irrational”. At some point over the past twenty-five years, Saddam Hussein, Mahmound Ahmadinejad, Hugo Chavez, Kim Jong-un, and Vladimir Putin, among others, have been branded “irrational”, “illogical”, “crazy”, “delusional”, or “mad”, and in some cases they have been likened to Adolf Hitler, who is often portrayed as the poster child of irrationality.
Whether this imprudent habit is to achieve political propaganda or American leaders truly believe their enemies are most often irrational, their view has vastly influenced the academic circles of traditional international relation.
Yes, I believe by now we have all heard of the Nobel Prize laurate, Daniel Kahneman, and learned that individuals don’t always act rationally, that individuals aren’t first and foremost foresighted utility maximizers, but react to changes in terms of gains and losses. And yes, I have repeated the word individual three times on purpose. But what about a group of individuals? What about a state? So back to the question, the majority of times
Do states act rationally?
How State Think: The Rationality of Foreign Policy is a book that argues that, throughout history, states predominantly act rationally. Some of the terrorists, fascists, tyrants, and the seemingly insane decisions they have made were in fact, rational. There were cases where rational decisions led to disastrous outcomes and irrational actions somehow achieved positive results. Outcomes and morality should not be what we define rationality. So what defines political rationality? In defiance of the prevalent doctrine of expected utility maximization, the authors bring to the fore two perspectives in reimagining rationality amidst information scarce environments. They accentuate the importance of leaders guided by theoretical frameworks and prioritizing process over outcomes.
The authors argue that majority of times, states act according to goal and strategic rationality at both individual and collective levels. The goal-rational states are primarily motivated to pursue self-preservation or survival and there are two elements central to their approach: decisions are informed by credible theories and a thorough deliberative process. Credible theory refers to a set of realistic assumptions and causal logics, buttressed by empirical claims with solid historical evidence. Deliberation is characterized as a two-step aggregation process, built upon a robust and uninhibited debate and methodical evaluation of options, leading to a definitive decision. If states deviate from these criteria, they will fall into irrationality.
In the framework presented by Mearsheimer and Rosato, non-rational behaviors are considered as anomalies rather than the norm, typically arising from constraints or unpredictable black swan events in international politics. The subsequent narrative finally delves into the empirical question: "Throughout history, do states consistently act rationally?" Applying their theory to two real-world scenarios—grand strategy and crisis decisions—the authors examined ten historical cases, five for each scenario, traditionally perceived as non-rational, aiming to challenge this perspective. These case studies encompass pivotal moments such as Germany's pre-First World War decisions, Japan's strategic maneuvers in the 1930s culminating in Pearl Harbor, and US actions during both the Cuban Missile Crisis and the post-Cold War NATO expansion. The book also acknowledges instances where state actions deviate from rationality, citing examples like the US-backed Bay of Pigs invasion in 1961 and the 2003 invasion of Iraq.
Some of the examples mentioned in the book were intriguing. For example, it is widely believe in the West that Russian president Vladimir Putin’s decision to invade Ukraine was not a rational act. U.S senator Mitt Romney noted that “by invading Ukraine, Mr. Putin has already proved that he is capable of illogical and self-defeating decisions.” In the current days, the only morally acceptable reason for going to war is self-defence, and from the West’s viewpoint, the invasion of Ukraine was nothing but a war of conquest. So with the “unprovoked” assault, Putin joined a long line of irrational tyrants succumbed to his ego-driven obsession with restoring Russia’s great power.
But in fact, Putin and his advisers did, numerous times, expressed their concern thinking in a straightforward balance of power theory, viewing the West’s efforts to make Ukraine a bulwark on Russia’s boarder as an existential threat that could not be allowed to stand. Putin laid out his theory and logic in a speech explaining his decision for war: “With NATO’s eastward expansion the situation for Russia has been becoming worse and more dangerous by the year…We cannot stay idle and passively observe these developments. This would be an irresponsible thing to do for us….it is a red line which we have spoken about in numerous occasions. They have crossed it.” It is worth noting that Moscow preferred to deal with the growing threat on its borders through aggressive diplomacy, but the United States and its allies were unwilling to accommodate Russia’s security concerns. This being the case, Putin opted for war.
Does this make Putin’s action righteous? No, no one is saying that. But, per theory, he wasn’t irrational.
Please don’t shoot the authors yet. It is not their intention to justify the moral righteousness of any violence. There is a powerful tendency to equate rationality with morality since both qualities are thought to be features of enlightened thinking. Yet, rational decisions in international politics just rests on credible theories about how the world works, what the state is trying to achieve, what were the choices, what could be the repercussions, and emerge from a deliberative decision-making process. All of this means that Russia’s decision to invade Ukraine was rational.
There were other interesting examples laid out throughout the book, and overall I did enjoy reading them. Yet there are still some questionable aspects of this book that I would recommend readers to keep in mind while reading.
Upon initial perusal, the book presents a neat and sweeping theoretical set up with thorough historical analyses. However, upon deeper scrutiny, certain conceptual and empirical deficiencies come to light. Initially, the authors critique a range of theories they deem non-credible, including the clash of civilizations and racial theories. Notably, they scrutinize the audience costs theory, which posits that democratically elected leaders excel at signaling resolve in crises due to public commitment pressures, citing its insufficient empirical backing. Yet, this judgement may overlook recent research suggesting the efficacy of public posturing across various regime types. This is particularly relevant as the book heavily relies on references dating back over a decade, prompting reflection on the evolving nature of credibility and the influence of new evidence. Moreover, it raises a deeper and broader question: Who gets to determine what qualifies as credible? What is deemed credible could be later rendered noncredible as new evidence became available and vice versa. the subjective nature of interpretations, shaped by individual experiences and beliefs, further complicates endeavors to establish intersubjective understanding in such evaluations.
In addition, the book's evidence of certain historical events appears somewhat lacking in strength and depth. Concerns arise from serious misrepresentations of key historical cases, notably Japan's actions from 1937 to 1941. The portrayal of Japan as acting with restraint and reacting to Western external aggression contradicts mainstream historiography, rich in evidence from events like the Mukden incident (1931) and the Marco Polo Bridge incident (1937). Japan's invasion of Manchuria, and the Rape of Nanking, the Nanjing Massacre, where Japan military slaughtered 200,000 Chinese in killing contests and tortured 80,000 women and kids during the war is carved in mainstream historiography, there is broad consensus on how Japan's actions during this period were aggressive and expansionist, driven by its own imperial ambitions. In such cases, it is hard to brushed it off as “self-defence acting with restraint”. Such discrepancies cast some doubt on the accuracy and reliability of the book's arguments.
Overall, it is still an interesting read. It is rare to find political rationality defined in other literature, and I appreciate the authors’ detailed theory-based approach and historical case studies. -
ChuckIntoTheBin#16:
How States Think: The Rationality of Foreign Policy (2023, Yale University Press)
"The authors focus on the rationality of the foreign-policy decision making process (instrumental rationality), rather than goals or outcomes," "Rational actors often fail [...] because of factors they can neither anticipate nor control [...] If nonrationality is the norm, state behavior can be neither understood nor predicted, and studying international politics is a futile endeavor"
The only thing separating a fourth grader, fresh on his basic critical thinking skills, and the editorial team at Yale University Press before this "masterpiece" hit the shelves, is the former's lack of a corrupting social network and vested interests strong enough to cloud his judgment into publishing something this fallacious, intellectually parochial, and arguably incoherent.
Since when does rationality focus on outcomes? "Rather than"? Do we live on the same planet?
Nonrationality does not imply randomness or unpredictability. Unless you're omniscient or strictly writing perfectly resourced history, I'd argue that 'neither anticipate nor control' implies unpredictability, which situates you in a state of contradiction, in what seems to be a 'futile endeavor' of a book. 1/5. -
I think authors John Mearsheimer and Sebastian Rosato set out to make this an interesting read but unfortunately fell short, at least for the first half of the book, which was dry to say the least. The question is: do leaders and countries make rational decisions, particularly when it comes to international politics? The assumption is that they do, even if it is only for the sake of their own survival. The second half of the book, made up mostly of case studies, was a lot more interesting as it examines when they do make rational (sane) choices and times when they fall short, particularly in the context of world events, like both world wars. If you are interested in the subject, I would recommend.
-
The book provides criteria and an analytical methodology for understanding how states make decisions. In that regard the book is useful in evaluating arguments and situations.
I should add that the book's focus is on the decision makers which will generally be a very small number of elite--and may boil down to one person. The book seems to ignore the influence of the vast population of states under the decision makers.
The book maintains that state survival is practically always the top goal but for a state's policy makers on behalf of the state. But that is not the same as survival of the number one decisionmaker and that person's close circle. -
The first half of the book is very theoretical and provides and describes several frameworks, themes and topics. Sometimes, it was too descriptive and honestly boring. The second half is more interesting because it talks about many instances when states acted rationally and irrationally. In my opinion, I would like to see the two halves combined into each other and when there would be a description of rational behaviour then immediately there would be a real-world example. Otherwise, it is a well-written book.
-
A study of world governments and their leaders, with the guiding question being Do governments and their leaders act rationally? I think most people know the answer is that they sometimes do not and there is a lot of evidence that they don’t; in fact, according to the authors they rarely do, and they provide a lot of case studies to prove their point. Interesting book that I recommend.
-
An excellent and insightful read. For an enthusiast in international affairs, this book gave light to the theories and historical recounts on how rational, mostly, if not all states, would see geopolitics.
-
An interesting book that presents a perspective against commonly held beliefs in the world of foreign policy. The first half is more about the introduction of theories; the second half is perhaps more interesting with real world examples and interpretations.
-
I like his pragmatic way of thinking, he is more realistic than many authors I know.
-
What does it mean for a state to be rational, the scholars ask. Well, the state must rely on a “credible theory.” And who determines whether the theory is credible? We the scholars do of course.
-
interesting structured insight about rationality, a bit dry overall interesting
-
كتاب مهم في مجال العلاقات الدولية والفكر الجيوسياسي يناقش المؤلفان فيه عقلانية الدول في صنع قرارتها، جون ميرشايمر هو منظّر الواقعية الهجومية.
كتاب مثير